I | INTRODUCTION |
Unemployment, enforced idleness of wage earners who
are able and willing to work but cannot find jobs. In societies in which most
people can earn a living only by working for others, being unable to find a job
is a serious problem. Because of its human costs in deprivation and a feeling of
rejection and personal failure, the extent of unemployment is widely used as a
measure of workers' welfare. The proportion of workers unemployed also shows how
well a nation's human resources are used and serves as an index of economic
activity.
II | MEASUREMENT |
The most common method of measuring
unemployment was developed in the U.S. in the 1930s; it is followed by many
other countries on the recommendation of the International Labor Organization.
In a monthly survey of a sample of households representing the entire civilian
population, information is obtained about the activity of each person of working
age (16 years of age or older in the U.S.). To ensure precision and ease of
recollection, the interviewers ask what people were doing in a single week. A
person who did any work during that week for pay or profit, worked 15 hours or
more as an unpaid worker in a family business, or had a job from which he or she
was temporarily absent, is counted as employed. A person who was not working but
was looking for work or was on a temporary layoff and available to take a job is
counted as unemployed. The number of unemployed is then divided by the number of
people in the civilian labor force (that is, the sum of the employed and the
unemployed) in order to calculate the unemployment rate. In the U.S., statistics
for states and local areas are based partly on the same survey and partly on
estimates of unemployment built up from unemployment-insurance records; these
records, however, do not include all the unemployed, since many people who are
seeking work are not eligible to receive unemployment compensation (see
Unemployment Insurance).
In some countries, instead of a special
survey, unemployment estimates are developed from data on the number of people
who are looking for work through the public employment offices or the number
receiving unemployment compensation payments.
III | CAUSES |
Economists have described the causes of
unemployment as frictional, seasonal, structural, and cyclical.
Frictional unemployment arises because
workers seeking jobs do not find them immediately; while looking for work they
are counted as unemployed. Friction in this case refers to the
incongruity between the demand for and supply of labor. The amount of frictional
unemployment depends on the frequency with which workers change jobs and the
time it takes to find new ones. Job changes occur often in the U.S.: A January
1983 survey showed that more than 25 percent of all workers had been with their
current employers one year or less. About a quarter of those unemployed at any
particular time are employed one month later. This means that a considerable
degree of unemployment in the U.S. is frictional and lasts only a short time.
This type of unemployment could be reduced somewhat by more efficient placement
services. When workers are free to quit their jobs, however, some frictional
unemployment will always be present.
Seasonal unemployment occurs when industries
have a slow season, such as construction and other outdoor work in winter. It
also occurs at the end of the school year in June, when large numbers of
students and graduates look for work. At its seasonal high point (January and
February), unemployment in the U.S. between 1976 and 1986 was typically 20
percent higher than at the seasonal low (October).
Structural unemployment arises from an
imbalance between the kinds of workers wanted by employers and the kinds of
workers looking for jobs. The imbalances may be caused by inadequacy in skills,
location, or personal characteristics. Technological developments, for example,
necessitate new skills in many industries, leaving those workers who have
outdated skills without a job. A plant in a declining industry may close down or
move to another area, throwing out of work those employees who are unable or
unwilling to move. Workers with inadequate education or training and young
workers with little or no experience may be unable to get jobs because employers
believe that these employees would not produce enough to be worth paying the
legal minimum wage or the rate agreed on with the union. On the other hand, even
highly trained workers can be unemployed; this happened in the U.S. in the early
1970s, for example, when the large numbers of new graduates with doctoral
degrees in physics and mathematics exceeded the number of jobs available in
those fields. If employers practice illegal job discrimination against any group
because of sex, race, religion, age, or national origin, a high unemployment
rate for these workers could result even when jobs are plentiful. Structural
unemployment shows up most prominently in some cities, in some occupations or
industries, for those with below-average educational attainments, and for some
other groups in the labor force. In June 1992, for example, when the U.S.
civilian unemployment rate was 7.8 percent, the rate in the state of New York
was 9.2 percent; for teenagers 16 to 19, 23.6 percent; for black workers, 14.9
percent; and for retail workers, 9.2 percent.
Cyclical unemployment results from a general
lack of demand for labor. When the business cycle turns downward, demand for
goods and services drops; consequently, workers are laid off. In the 19th
century, the U.S. experienced depressions roughly every 20 years. A long and
severe depression occurred in the 1890s, when unemployment reached about 18
percent of the civilian labor force, and four less-severe depressions occurred
in the first quarter of the 20th century. The worst depression in U.S. history
was in the 1930s; at its height, one worker in four was unemployed, and some
remained out of work for years. See Business Cycle.
IV | GOVERNMENT INVOLVEMENT |
As a result of this depression, the U.S.
government took steps to alleviate unemployment. In the mid-1930s millions of
jobs were provided by public works and other special programs. Notable among the
federal agencies established to carry out these programs were the Civilian
Conservation Corps and the National Youth Administration, which employed young
workers on a wide variety of projects; and the Work Projects Administration,
which embarked on a broad program involving both public-works construction and
cultural and recreational activities.
Another New Deal measure was the Social
Security Act of 1935, which set up the first comprehensive social-insurance
system in the U.S. (see Social Security). It introduced unemployment
insurance, providing workers who lose their jobs with a weekly compensation
payment. By maintaining the workers' purchasing power, unemployment insurance
reduces cyclical swings in demand, thus helping trade and industry.
The enactment of various laws aimed at
reviving business and industrial activity resulted in a substantial improvement
in U.S. economic conditions and a decline in unemployment. Soon after the
outbreak of World War II in September 1939, the U.S. government launched a
program for expanding and modernizing the national defense system. The program
provided industry with a powerful stimulus, and unemployment rapidly declined.
After the U.S. entered the war in December 1941, not only was the goal of full
employment attained, but a shortage of labor replaced the previous shortage of
jobs.
In the postwar period a major new measure was
passed by the Congress. The Employment Act of 1946 proclaimed that the federal
government would take the responsibility for maintaining high employment levels,
economic stability, and growth; that is, the government would coordinate its
economic policies (such as those on taxation, expenditures, foreign trade, and
control of money, credit, and banking) in such a way as to prevent serious
depressions. A Council of Economic Advisers was set up to monitor the economy
and provide advice to the president and Congress. Between 1945 and 1990 nine
cyclical swings in unemployment occurred; all were smaller than the 1930s
depression. During this period the unemployment rate was as low as 2.9 percent
(1953) and as high as 9.7 percent (1982). Because of cutbacks in the
unemployment insurance program and changes in the nature of employment during
the 1980s, however, only 37 percent of jobless workers received benefits in
1990.
Fears that the introduction of automation and
other labor-saving technology would increase unemployment have led some workers
to oppose such changes. Labor-saving methods, however, increase output per
worker and make possible rising levels of worker income. In order to deal with
the effects of technological change, the government passed several acts, such as
the Manpower Training and Development Act (1962), the Comprehensive Employment
and Training Act (1973), and the Job Training Partnership Act (1982), to set up
programs designed to train the unemployed in those skills in which there was
employment opportunity.
A major policy issue is the relation of
unemployment to inflation. In theory, when demand for labor rises to the point
at which unemployment is low and employers find it difficult to hire qualified
workers, wages increase, pushing production costs and prices higher and thus
contributing to inflation; when demand declines and unemployment increases,
inflationary pressures on wages and production costs are relieved. Confounding
this theory, however, both inflation and unemployment rates were high in the
1970s. The government adopted policies to control inflation that involved
reducing demand in the economy in the expectation that one of the costs of
lowering inflation would be rising unemployment. Indeed, the unemployment rate
rose from 5.8 percent in 1979 to 9.7 percent by 1982 before dropping back to
between 5 and 7 percent in the mid- and late 1980s.
V | UNEMPLOYMENT IN OTHER NATIONS |
The post-World War II period in Europe was
characterized by sharp rises in unemployment resulting from the wartime
destruction of many industries, the addition to the labor force of large numbers
of war veterans, and a variety of consequent economic maladjustments. U.S. aid
helped the highly successful efforts of Western European countries to
rehabilitate their industries and provide employment for their workers (see
European Recovery Program).
Most of the major nonsocialist industrialized
countries had lower rates of unemployment than the U.S. by the 1950s. In the
1960s, when the U.S. unemployment rate averaged 5-6 percent, only Canada had a
higher rate (7 percent); Italy had a rate of 4 percent, and all the other
Western European industrial nations, as well as Japan, had rates of about 2
percent or less. Attempts to explain these disparities focused on social and
economic differences among nations, including the following: the more rapid
growth of the labor force in the U.S.; more years of schooling in the U.S., with
many students working part-time and seeking jobs frequently; measures taken in
European countries to reduce seasonal unemployment by spreading work over the
year; European practices of placing youth in their midteens into apprenticeship
and other work-training arrangements that promote job stability; legal
restraints in some countries against laying off workers; extensive retraining
programs for unemployed workers to update their skills; and greater attachment
of workers to their jobs in both Europe and Japan. By early 1992 Japan's
unemployment rate was still low (just over 2 percent), despite an economic
slowdown, but the rate was approaching 10 percent in Britain and France and
generally exceeded that rate in Eastern Europe, where formerly socialist
economies were adjusting to free-market capitalism.
The Soviet Union maintained no statistics on
unemployment, nor did it have unemployment insurance. Generally, workers were
kept on the payroll whether or not they were needed, making for a low
productivity rate. In early 1992, unemployment in Russia was reported to be less
than 1 percent, but the government was opening unemployment offices, preparing
for an increase as more people began working in the private sector.
In developing nations in Asia, Africa, and
Latin America a much more serious and widespread problem is underemployment—that
is, people are employed only part time or at work that is inefficient or
unproductive, with a correspondingly low income that is insufficient to meet
their needs. Much of the unemployment and underemployment in developing nations
has accompanied migration from rural to larger urban centers.
In industrialized countries, with unemployment
insurance and other forms of income maintenance, unemployment does not cause as
great a hardship as it once did. Measures to stabilize the economy have made
economic downturns briefer and less severe. Workers are still threatened by long
periods of unemployment, however, and some workers bear a disproportionate
burden. The problem of modern governments is how to get the benefits of economic
flexibility and rising productivity while reducing the number of unemployed
workers, keeping their spells of joblessness short, maintaining their income,
and helping them return to work with viable skills.
No comments:
Post a Comment