I | INTRODUCTION |
Taxation, system of raising money to finance
government. All governments require payments of money—taxes—from people.
Governments use tax revenues to pay soldiers and police, to build dams and
roads, to operate schools and hospitals, to provide food to the poor and medical
care to the elderly, and for hundreds of other purposes. Without taxes to fund
its activities, government could not exist.
Throughout history, people have debated the
amount and kinds of taxes that a government should impose, as well as how it
should distribute the burden of those taxes across society. Unpopular taxes have
caused public protests, riots, and even revolutions. In political campaigns,
candidates’ views on taxation may partly determine their popularity with
voters.
Taxation is the most important source of
revenues for modern governments, typically accounting for 90 percent or more of
their income. The remainder of government revenue comes from borrowing and from
charging fees for services. Countries differ considerably in the amount of taxes
they collect. In the United States, about 30 percent of the gross
domestic product (GDP), a measure of economic output, went for tax payments in
2000. The 30 percent figure is relatively low from a historical standpoint. As a
result of a new round of tax cuts in 2003, the tax percentage share of GDP was
expected to be lower than at any time since 1959 when many major government
programs, such as Medicare and Medicaid, did not exist. In Canada about 35
percent of the country’s gross domestic product goes for taxes. In France the
figure is 45 percent, and in Sweden it is 51 percent.
In addition to using taxation to raise money,
governments may raise or lower taxes to achieve social and economic objectives,
or to achieve political popularity with certain groups. Taxation can
redistribute a society’s wealth by imposing a heavier tax burden on one group in
order to fund services for another. Also, some economists consider taxation an
important tool for maintaining the stability of a country’s economy.
II | TYPES OF TAXES |
Governments impose many types of taxes. In
most developed countries, individuals pay income taxes when they earn money,
consumption taxes when they spend it, property taxes when they own a home or
land, and in some cases estate taxes when they die. In the United States,
federal, state, and local governments all collect taxes.
Taxes on people’s incomes play critical roles
in the revenue systems of all developed countries. In the United States,
personal income taxation is the single largest source of revenue for the federal
government. In 2002 it accounted for about 48.8 percent of all federal revenues.
Payroll taxes, which are used to finance social insurance programs such as
Social Security and Medicare, account for 36.4 percent of federal revenues. The
United States also taxes the incomes of corporations. In 2002 corporate income
taxation accounted for 10.4 percent of federal revenues.
State and local governments depend on sales
taxes and property taxes as their main sources of funding. Most U.S. states also
tax the incomes of individuals and corporations, although less heavily than the
federal government. All Canadian provinces collect income taxes from individuals
and corporations.
A | Individual Income Tax |
An individual income tax, also called a
personal income tax, is a tax on a person’s income. Income includes wages,
salaries, and other earnings from one’s occupation; interest earned by savings
accounts and certain types of bonds; rents (earnings from rented properties);
royalties earned on sales of patented or copyrighted items, such as inventions
and books; and dividends from stock. Income also includes capital gains,
which are profits from the sale of stock, real estate, or other investments
whose value has increased over time.
The national governments of the United
States, Canada, and many other countries require citizens to file an individual
income tax return each year. Each taxpayer must compute his or her tax
liability—the amount of money he or she owes the government. This computation
involves four major steps. (1) The taxpayer computes adjusted gross
income—one’s income from all taxable sources minus certain expenses incurred
in earning that income. (2) The taxpayer converts adjusted gross income to
taxable income—the amount of income subject to tax—by subtracting various
amounts called exemptions and deductions. Some deductions exist to
enhance the fairness of the tax system. For example, the U.S. government permits
a deduction for extraordinarily high medical expenses. Other deductions are
allowed to encourage certain kinds of behavior. For example, some governments
permit deductions of charitable contributions as an incentive for individuals to
give money to worthy causes. (3) The taxpayer calculates the amount of tax due
by consulting a tax table, which shows the exact amount of tax due for
most levels of taxable income. People with very high incomes consult a rate
schedule, a list of tax rates for different ranges of taxable income, to
compute the amount of tax due. (4) The taxpayer subtracts taxes paid during the
year and any allowable tax credits to arrive at final tax liability.
After computing the amount of tax due, the
taxpayer must send this information to the government and enclose the amount
due. In 2001 the average taxpayer in the United States paid about 15 percent of
his or her income in income taxes. Many taxpayers, rather than owing money,
receive a refund from the government after filing a tax return, typically
because they had too much tax withheld from their wages and salaries during the
year. Low-income workers in the United States may also receive a refund because
of the earned income tax credit, a federal government subsidy for the
working poor.
Income taxation enjoys widespread support
because income is considered a good indicator of an individual’s ability to pay.
However, income taxes are hard to administer because measuring income is often
difficult. For example, some people receive part of their income “in-kind”—in
the form of goods and services rather than in cash. Farmers provide field hands
with food, and corporations may give employees access to company cars and free
parking spaces. If governments tax cash income but not in-kind compensation,
then people can avoid taxation by taking a higher proportion of their income as
in-kind compensation.
The Internal Revenue Service (IRS), an
agency of the Department of the Treasury, administers the federal income tax in
the United States. Canada Customs and Revenue Agency, which operates under the
Minister of National Revenue, administers the tax in Canada.
B | Corporate Income Tax |
All corporations in the United States and
Canada must pay tax on their net income (profits) to the federal government and
also to most state or provincial governments. U.S. corporate tax rates generally
increase with income. For example, in 2001 corporations with profits of up to
$50,000 paid 15 percent in taxes, whereas corporations with profits greater than
about $18.3 million were taxed at a flat rate of 35 percent. In Canada the basic
rate for corporations was 28 percent in 2000.
The corporate income tax is one of the
most controversial types of taxes. Although the law treats corporations as if
they have an independent ability to pay a tax, many economists note that only
real people—such as the shareholders who own corporations—can bear a tax burden.
In addition, the corporate income tax leads to double taxation of corporate
income. Income is taxed once when it is earned by the corporation, and a second
time when it is paid out to shareholders in the form of dividends. Thus,
corporate income faces a higher tax burden than income earned by individuals or
by other types of businesses. Tax legislation passed in 2003 in the United
States attempted to address this issue by lowering the tax rate on
dividends.
Some economists have proposed abolishing
the corporate income tax and instead taxing the owners of corporations
(shareholders) through the personal income tax. Other students of the tax system
see the corporate income tax as the price corporations pay in return for special
privileges from society. The most important of these privileges is limited
liability for shareholders. This means that creditors cannot claim the
personal assets of shareholders, because the liability of shareholders for the
corporation’s debts is limited to the amount they have invested in the
corporation.
C | Payroll Tax |
Whereas an income tax is levied on all
sources of income, a payroll tax applies only to wages and salaries.
Employers automatically withhold payroll taxes from employees’ wages and forward
them to the government. Payroll taxes are the main sources of funding for
various social insurance programs, such as those that provide benefits to the
poor, elderly, unemployed, and disabled. In 2002 payroll taxes accounted for
about 36.4 percent of all federal tax revenues in the United States; in Canada,
the figure was 21 percent. For most people, payroll taxes are the second-largest
tax they must pay each year, after individual income taxes.
The U.S. federal government levies the
Social Security and Medicare payroll taxes at a flat rate. In 2003 the rate was
7.65 percent for employees and 15.3 percent for the self-employed. Of the 7.65
percent, 6.2 percent goes for Social Security and 1.45 percent for Medicare. The
rate is based on annual gross income up to a certain limit. The limit was
$87,000 in 2003. The limit rises each year at the same rate as the growth in
average wages. The government imposes no payroll tax on earnings above the
limit. Employers pay half the tax and employees pay the other half. The Medicare
payroll tax is 2.9 percent of all earnings, with no cap. Again, employers and
employees split the cost of the tax. Self-employed individuals must pay the
entire payroll tax.
Although the legislators who set up
payroll taxes intended to divide the tax burden equally between employers and
employees, this may not occur in practice. Some economists believe that the tax
causes employers to offer lower pretax wages to employees than they would
otherwise, in effect shifting the tax burden entirely to employees.
D | Consumption Taxes |
A consumption tax is a tax levied
on sales of goods or services. The most important kinds of consumption taxes are
general sales taxes, excise taxes, value-added taxes, and tariffs.
In the United States, consumption taxes
account for only 3.3 percent of all federal tax revenues. This is considerably
lower than in most other countries. In Canada, the figure is 24 percent. General
sales taxes and excise taxes are the largest sources of revenue for state and
local governments in the United States, accounting for about 36 percent of their
total tax revenues.
D1 | General Sales Taxes |
A general sales tax imposes the
same tax rate on a wide variety of goods and, in some cases, services. In the
United States, most states and many local governments have a general sales tax.
The country has no national general sales tax. State sales taxes range from 3 to
7 percent, and local sales taxes range from a fraction of 1 percent to 7
percent. In Canada, all provinces except Alberta impose a general sales tax on
goods. In some provinces, the provincial sales tax and the federal goods and
services tax (GST) are combined into a single tax known as the harmonized sales
tax (HST). Local governments in Canada do not have the authority to impose
general sales taxes.
Although sellers are legally responsible
for paying sales taxes, and sellers collect sales taxes from consumers, the
burden of any given sales tax is often divided between sellers and consumers
(for more information, see the Effects of Taxes section of this article).
Most states exempt certain necessities from sales tax, such as basic groceries
and prescription drugs. Both individuals and businesses pay sales tax. See
Sales Tax.
D2 | Excise Taxes |
Federal, state, and local governments
levy excise taxes, which are sales taxes on specific goods or services.
Excise taxes are also called selective sales taxes. Goods subject to
excise taxes in the United States and Canada include tobacco products, alcoholic
beverages, gasoline, and some luxury items. Excise taxes are applied either on a
per unit basis, such as per package of cigarettes or per liter or gallon of
gasoline, or as a fixed percentage of the sales price.
Governments sometimes levy excise taxes
to pay for specific projects. For example, voters in a city might approve a tax
on hotel rooms to help pay for a new convention center. Some national
governments impose an excise tax on airline tickets to help pay for airport
improvements or airline security. Revenues from gasoline taxes typically pay for
highway construction and improvements. Excise taxes designed to limit
consumption of a commodity, such as taxes on cigarettes and alcoholic beverages,
are commonly known as “sin taxes.”
Another type of excise tax is the
license tax. Most states require people to buy licenses to engage in
certain activities, such as hunting and fishing, operating a motor vehicle,
owning a business, and selling alcoholic beverages. See Excise Tax.
D3 | Value-Added Tax |
In Canada and Europe the favored form of
consumption taxation is a value-added tax (VAT). In this system, the
seller pays the government a percentage of the value added to goods or services
at each stage of production. The value added at each stage of production is the
difference between the seller’s costs for materials and the selling price. In
essence, a VAT is just a general sales tax that is collected at multiple
stages.
In the production of apple pies, for
example, the farmer grows apples and sells them to a baker, who turns them into
a pie. The baker sells the pie to a restaurant owner, who sells it to a
consumer. At each stage, the producer adds value to the commodity by processing
it with capital (machines) and labor. The farmer, the baker, and the restaurant
owner each charge their customer a VAT. However, they can each claim a credit to
recover the tax they paid on purchases related to their commercial activities.
See Value-Added Tax.
Canada’s VAT, adopted in 1991, is known
as the goods and services tax (GST). In 2003 the GST was 7 percent on most goods
and services in Canada. The government exempts certain goods and services from
the tax, including most food, most medical and dental services, child-care
services, and previously owned residential housing.
D4 | Tariffs |
Tariffs, also called duties or customs duties,
are taxes levied on imported or exported goods. Import duties are considered
consumption taxes because they are levied on goods to be consumed. Import duties
also protect domestic industries from foreign competition by making imported
goods more expensive than their domestic counterparts. In the United States,
import duties were the largest source of federal revenues until the introduction
of the income tax in 1913. Today they account for only a small portion of
federal revenues.
For general information on tariffs,
see Tariff. For a history of tariffs in the United States, see
Tariffs, United States.
E | Property Taxes |
In principle, a property tax is a
tax on an individual’s wealth—the value of all of the person’s assets, both
financial (such as stocks and bonds) and real (such as houses, cars, and
artwork). In practice, property taxes are usually more limited. In the United
States, state and local governments generally levy property taxes on
buildings—such as homes, office buildings, and factories—and on land. There is
no federal property tax. In 2000 property taxes accounted for 2.0 percent of
state tax revenues and 72 percent of local tax revenues. The Canadian
constitution allows the federal government to levy property taxes. However,
currently only local and provincial governments collect property taxes. The
property tax is by far the largest source of revenue for local governments.
The property tax is often unpopular with
homeowners. One reason is that, because homes are not sold very often,
governments must levy the tax on the estimated value of the dwelling.
Some citizens believe that the government overvalues their homes, leading to
unfairly high property tax burdens.
F | Estate, Inheritance, and Gift Taxes |
When a person dies, the property that he
or she leaves for others may be subject to tax. An estate tax is a tax on
the deceased person’s estate, which includes everything the person owned at the
time of death—money, real estate, stock, bonds, proceeds from insurance
policies, and material possessions. Most governments levy estate taxes before
the deceased person’s property passes to heirs, although many governments do not
impose an estate tax on property inherited by a spouse. An inheritance
tax also taxes the value of the deceased person’s estate, but after the
estate passes to heirs. The inheritors pay the tax. Estate and inheritance taxes
are sometimes collectively called death taxes. A gift tax is a tax
on the transfer of property between living people.
In the United States, the federal
government imposes gift and estate taxes, and some states impose inheritance or
estate taxes. However, they are usually minor sources of revenue because the
taxes apply only to very large estates and gifts. Property transferred to a
deceased person’s spouse is not taxed. Under the Economic Growth and Tax Relief
Reconciliation Act of 2001, estate taxes were to be gradually lowered and then
phased out altogether in 2010. Under the new law, the exemption for estate taxes
was to rise from $1 million in 2002 to $3.5 million in 2009. However, the new
law itself was due to be repealed on the eve of 2011, reverting to the
legislation that existed prior to the passage of the act unless Congress agreed
to extend it. These so-called “sunset” provisions are often enacted as a result
of legislative compromises. Opponents of the provision agree to support a tax
bill only if the provision is due to expire. Proponents of the provision agree
to the compromise because they anticipate that the provision will prove popular
and will be extended.
In 2002 less than 2 percent of the people
who died in the United States had estates that were subject to the estate tax.
In 2002 federal gift-tax law allowed each individual to give any other person up
to $11,000 per year tax-free. The Tax Relief Reconciliation Act amended other
provisions of the gift tax as well. In Canada, there are currently no death
taxes, although both the federal and provincial governments levied estate taxes
in the past.
Estate and gift taxes are controversial.
Proponents argue that they are useful tools for distributing wealth more equally
in society and preventing the rise of powerful oligarchies. Opponents argue that
it is a person’s right to pass on property to his or her heirs, and the
government has no right to interfere. If an individual has paid tax on his or
her income while in the process of accumulating wealth, critics ask, why should
it be taxed again when the wealth is transferred? Others argue that estate and
gift taxes discourage individuals from working and saving to accumulate wealth
to leave to their children. On the other hand, the presence of an estate tax
might encourage people to accumulate greater wealth in order to reach a given
after-tax goal. See Estate Tax. See also Gift Tax.
G | Other Taxes |
A poll tax, also called a
lump-sum tax or head tax, collects the same amount of money from
each individual regardless of income or circumstances. Poll taxes are not widely
used because their burden falls hardest on the poor. When the British government
implemented a system of local poll taxes in 1990, citizens considered the tax so
unfair that they held demonstrations—some violent—around the country. The
extreme unpopularity of the tax contributed to the downfall of Prime Minister
Margaret Thatcher. Her successor, John Major, repealed the tax in 1991. In the
United States, the 24th Amendment, ratified in 1964, prohibited the payment of
poll taxes as a requirement for voting in federal elections. Until that time, a
number of Southern states had used poll taxes to deny poor blacks the right to
vote. See Poll Tax.
A pollution tax is a tax levied on
a company that produces air, water, or soil pollution over a certain level
established by the government. The tax provides an incentive for companies to
pollute less and thus reduce damage to the environment. The United States,
France, Germany, and The Netherlands all levy taxes on some types of pollution.
However, these taxes account for just a tiny amount of total tax revenue. In
Canada, some provincial governments levy pollution taxes.
III | HOW GOVERNMENT SPENDS TAXES |
Governments spend the revenues raised by
taxation on an enormous variety of items, from atomic weapons to drug-abuse
treatment programs. The annual budget published by the U.S. government requires
more than 1,000 pages to list and describe all of the various programs it pays
for.
Federal government spending comprises
several major categories. One of the largest government expenditures is national
defense. The most important nonmilitary program is Social Security, whose main
function is to provide income to individuals during their retirement years.
Another major program for the benefit of the elderly is Medicare, a health
insurance program. Social welfare programs—which include unemployment insurance
and payments of cash and food to the poor—also account for a large slice of the
federal budget (see Welfare).
When the government borrows money from the
public, it must pay interest like any other borrower. One popular way the
federal government borrows money is by selling U.S. treasury bonds. By
purchasing the bonds, individuals lend money to the government. At the end of a
bond’s term, the government returns the investment plus interest.
State and local governments spend the
largest share of their tax revenues on public school systems. Other important
expenditures include welfare programs, police and fire protection, maintenance
of roads and highways, and public hospitals.
IV | PRINCIPLES OF TAXATION |
Seventeenth-century French statesman
Jean-Baptiste Colbert declared, “The art of taxation is the art of plucking the
goose so as to get the largest possible amount of feathers with the least
possible squealing.” Today’s economists have rather different ideas of what
constitutes a good tax system. Most believe that a tax system should follow two
main principles: fairness and efficiency. Scottish economist Adam Smith laid out
these principles in his landmark treatise The Wealth of Nations (1776).
See the Sidebar “From The Wealth of Nations.”
A | Fairness |
Economists consider two principles of
fairness to determine whether the burden of a tax is distributed fairly: the
ability-to-pay principle and the benefits principle.
A1 | Ability-to-Pay Principle |
The ability-to-pay principle
holds that people’s taxes should be based upon their ability to pay, usually
as measured by income or wealth. One implication of this principle is
horizontal equity, which states that people in equal positions should pay
the same amount of tax. If two people both have incomes of $50,000, then
horizontal equity requires that they pay the same amount of tax. Suppose,
however, that two individuals both have incomes of $50,000, but one has a lot of
medical bills and the other is healthy. Are they in equal positions? If not,
then perhaps the tax burden of the person with medical bills should be reduced.
But by how much? And how does a person document to tax authorities that he or
she is truly paying medical costs, and not just pretending in order to lower the
tax bill? This example illustrates a fundamental dilemma in tax design: Fairness
is often the enemy of simplicity.
A second requirement of the
ability-to-pay principle is vertical equity, the idea that a tax system
should distribute the burden fairly across people with different abilities to
pay. This idea implies that a person with higher income should pay more in taxes
than one with less income. But how much more? Should families with different
incomes be taxed at the same rate or at different rates? Taxes may be
proportional, progressive, or regressive. A proportional tax takes the
same percentage of income from all people. A progressive tax takes a
higher percentage of income as income rises—rich people not only pay a larger
amount of money than poor people, but a larger fraction of their incomes. A
regressive tax takes a smaller percentage of income as income rises—poor
people pay a larger fraction of their incomes in taxes than rich people.
Which is fairest—a proportional,
progressive, or regressive system? There is no scientific way to resolve this
question. The answer depends on ethical and philosophical judgments, such as
whether a society has the right to take income from one group of people and give
it to another. A progressive, proportional, or even slightly regressive system
all can achieve vertical equity’s requirement that a richer person should pay
more in taxes than a poorer person. Most industrialized nations have progressive
income tax systems, which impose a heavier tax burden as one’s income increases.
In the United States, the individual income tax system divides taxable income
into different tax brackets—ranges of income with different tax rates.
Some economists consider sales taxes
regressive because individuals with higher incomes spend a smaller proportion of
their incomes on sales taxes than those with lower incomes. A poor person and a
rich person who spend the same amount on groceries each year will pay the same
amount in sales taxes, even though the rich person earns more money. However,
rich people consume more than poor people, and studies of people’s spending
patterns reveal that, over the course of a lifetime, the rich person will pay
roughly the same proportion of his or her income in sales taxes as the poor
person.
A2 | Benefits Principle |
The benefits principle of
taxation states that only the beneficiaries of a particular government program
should have to pay for it. The benefits principle regards public services as
similar to private goods and regards taxes as the price people must pay for
these services. The practical application of the benefits principle is extremely
limited, because most government services are consumed by the community as a
whole. For example, one cannot estimate the benefit received by a particular
individual for general public services such as national defense and local police
protection.
One can make a case that, for some
taxes, there is a relationship between taxes paid and benefits received.
Gasoline taxes, for example, are used to finance highway construction. But even
here, the link between taxes and benefits is weak. Some drivers have more
fuel-efficient cars than others. They may use the roads as much as other
drivers, but buy less gasoline and thus pay less tax. Merchants who operate
stores along the sides of highways benefit from the presence of the roads, but
the benefit has nothing to do with the merchants’ gasoline consumption. Despite
its intuitive appeal, the benefits principle is not important in practice, and
it plays little role in the design of tax systems.
B | Efficiency |
In addition to being fair, a good tax
system should be efficient, wasting as little money and resources as possible.
Three measures of efficiency are administration costs, compliance costs, and
excess burden.
B1 | Administration Costs |
Running a tax collection authority costs
money. The government must hire tax collectors to gather revenue, data entry
clerks to process tax returns, auditors to inspect questionable returns, lawyers
to handle disputes, and accountants to track the flow of money. No tax system is
perfectly efficient, but government should strive to minimize the costs of
administration.
B2 | Compliance Costs |
Complying with the system—paying
taxes—costs taxpayers money above and beyond the actual tax bill. These costs
include the money that people spend on accountants, tax lawyers, and tax
preparers, as well as the value of taxpayers’ time spent filling out tax returns
and keeping records.
B3 | Excess Burden |
A third measure of a tax system’s
efficiency takes into account the fact that when the government levies a tax on
a good, it distorts consumer behavior—people buy less of the taxed good and more
of other goods. Instead of choosing what goods to buy solely on the basis of
their intrinsic merits, consumers are influenced by taxes. This tax-induced
change in behavior is called an excess burden. The larger the excess
burden of a tax, the worse it is for efficiency.
Taxes on labor can also lead to excess
burdens. When the government taxes people’s labor (through an income tax),
people may decide to change the number of hours that they work. The tax distorts
their choice between working and leisure.
Not every tax generates an excess
burden. Consider a lump-sum tax—a fixed amount of money that all
taxpayers must pay regardless of their circumstances. If the government levies a
tax of $1,000 on each citizen, regardless of what he or she buys or earns, the
only way to avoid paying the tax is to leave the country or die. Citizens cannot
avoid the tax by changing their behavior. Because it does not distort behavior,
a lump-sum tax has no excess burden—it is perfectly efficient. However, most
people would perceive such a tax as extremely unfair because it disregards
individual circumstances such as a person’s ability to pay. Thus, the principles
of fairness and efficiency conflict: fairness comes at the cost of efficiency.
Each society must find the best tradeoff between fairness and efficiency, given
the ethical beliefs of its citizens.
V | EFFECTS OF TAXES |
Economists have devoted considerable effort
to studying the effects of taxes. In particular, they study how taxes affect
people’s behavior, including their choices in working, saving, and
investing.
To understand the effect of any tax, one must
first determine who bears the burden of the tax. This is not always an easy
task. Suppose that the price of a chocolate doughnut is $1.00. The government
then imposes on sellers a tax of 10 cents per doughnut. A few weeks after its
imposition, the tax causes the price to increase to $1.10. The doughnut seller
clearly receives the same amount per doughnut as he or she did before the
tax—the tax has not made the seller worse off. Consumers pay the entire tax in
the form of higher prices. On the other hand, suppose that after the tax the
price increases to $1.04. In this case, the seller keeps only 94 cents per
doughnut, and is worse off by 6 cents per doughnut. Consumers are also worse
off, however, because they have to pay 4 cents more per doughnut. In this case,
retailers and consumers share the burden of the tax.
The way a tax affects people is called the
tax incidence. The statutory incidence of a tax refers to the
individuals or groups who must legally pay the tax. The statutory incidence
reveals essentially nothing about a tax’s real burden, because as previously
illustrated, prices may change in response to a tax. In contrast, the
economic incidence of a tax refers to its actual effects on people’s
incomes. The economic incidence of a tax depends on how buyers and sellers of
the commodity react when the tax is imposed. The more sensitive consumers are to
changes in price, the easier it is for them to turn to other products when the
price goes up, in which case producers bear more of the tax burden. On the other
hand, if consumers purchase the same amount regardless of price, they bear the
whole burden.
A | Labor Supply |
An economy's labor supply is the
number of hours that people work. Taxes can affect the labor supply by
influencing people's decisions about whether to work and how much to work.
Suppose that an individual earns $10 per hour, and the government imposes a 40
percent tax on earnings. Then after tax, the individual receives only $6 per
hour ($10 minus $4 in taxes). The impact of such a tax is hard to predict. On
one hand, the tax lowers the cost to the individual of not working. For each
hour of leisure, the individual gives up only $6 instead of $10. In effect,
leisure has become cheaper, so the individual tends to consume more of it—that
is, to work less. On the other hand, with a lower wage, the individual must work
more hours to maintain the standard of living he or she had before the tax.
Thus, the tax simultaneously leads to two effects that work in opposite
directions.
However, empirical work—analysis based on
observation of real-world data—has suggested two important general tendencies.
First, for most men, the effect of taxes on hours of work is relatively small.
Second, the work-related decisions of married women are quite sensitive to
changes in taxes. Research suggests that a tax increase that lowered their wages
by 10 percent would lower the number of hours that married women work by about 5
percent.
B | Saving |
Saving is the portion of income that
is not spent. Might taxes levied on returns to saving (such as interest and
dividends) influence the amount people save? When a tax is levied on interest or
dividends, it reduces the reward for saving. For example, if an individual earns
10 percent interest on a savings account and faces a 20 percent income tax rate,
then he or she makes only an 8 percent return—the other 2 percent goes to the
government. This effect tends to reduce the amount of saving that an individual
does. On the other hand, when interest is taxed, an individual must save more to
achieve any particular savings goal. For example, if parents regularly save
money to accumulate enough for their child’s college tuition payments, and taxes
on interest increase, they must save more in order to reach their saving target.
This effect tends to increase the amount of saving. Because the two effects work
in opposite directions, in theory an increase in the tax on interest can
increase or decrease saving. Economists have devoted a great deal of effort to
studying people’s saving behavior. Although no firm consensus has emerged on the
impact that changes in interest and dividend tax rates have on saving, a
reasonable estimate is that such changes have a negligible effect.
C | Physical Investment |
Physical investment refers to the
purchase by businesses of manufactured aids to production. Physical investment
includes such items as machines, factories, computers, trucks, and office
furniture. The return on a physical investment is the amount by which the
investment increases the business’s revenues. How do taxes affect physical
investment? In effect, a tax on business income is a tax on the physical
investment’s return—the tax reduces the firm’s income and thus the benefit from
making the investment. Most economists believe that business taxes decrease the
amount of physical investment by businesses.
Taxes also influence the types of physical
investments that businesses make. This is because the government taxes returns
on some types of investments at higher rates than others. These differences
cause businesses to make investment decisions based on tax consequences, rather
than whether they are sound from a business point of view. By distorting
physical investment decisions, the tax system leads to an inefficient pattern of
investment.
D | Tax Evasion and Avoidance |
Tax evasion is failing to pay
legally due taxes. One important way that high tax rates affect behavior is by
increasing evasion. For example, people may fail to report income to the
government, thus reducing their tax bill and the government’s tax revenue. Tax
cheating is extremely difficult to measure. The Internal Revenue Service
estimates that taxpayers voluntarily pay only about 80 percent of the taxes they
legally owe. The greater an individual’s tax rate, the greater the incentive to
defraud the government.
Tax avoidance occurs when people
change their behavior to reduce the amount of taxes they legally owe. When
individuals relocate their business to a state with lower taxes or take
advantage of loopholes in tax laws, they are practicing tax avoidance. There is
nothing illegal about tax avoidance.
VI | HISTORY OF TAXATION |
For as long as governments have existed,
they have had to come up with ways to finance their activities. Methods of
public finance have changed enormously over time.
A | Ancient Times |
In the ancient civilizations of Palestine,
Egypt, Assyria, and Babylonia, individual property rights did not exist. The
king was sole owner of everything in his domain, including the bodies of his
subjects. Thus, instead of taxing individuals to support the government, the
king could simply force them to work for him. Ancient kings earned income in the
form of food from their lands and precious metals from their mines. If this
income did not meet the king’s demands, he might lead his armies into
neighboring countries to confiscate their property. The conquered peoples might
also be required to make payment (known as tribute) to the conqueror in
acknowledgment of their submission to his power. If kings were not very wealthy
or not very good at stealing from other countries, they would resort to taxing
their own people. In societies that operated without money, the ruler taxed
farmers by requiring that they turn over some proportion of their crops to the
state. Poll taxes were a major source of revenue in Egypt under the Ptolemaic
dynasty (323 bc-30 bc).
The government of ancient Athens, Greece,
relied on publicly owned silver mines, tribute from conquered countries, a few
customs duties, and voluntary contributions from citizens for revenue. It levied
poll taxes only on slaves and aliens (noncitizens) and made failure to pay a
capital crime.
In the early years of the Roman republic
all Roman citizens paid a poll tax. However, Roman military victories brought in
so much foreign tribute that the government exempted citizens from this tax in
the 2nd century bc, after the
Punic Wars between Rome and Carthage. More than 100 years later, Emperor
Augustus introduced land and inheritance taxes. Succeeding emperors raised rates
and found an increasing number of things to tax, including wheat and salt.
B | Medieval Times |
During the Middle Ages, from about the 5th
century ad to the 15th century,
taxation varied from region to region. Europeans were subject to many forms of
taxation, including land taxes, poll taxes, inheritance taxes, tolls (payments
for the use of bridges, roads, or seaports), and miscellaneous fees and fines.
Many people paid taxes in the form of money or crops directly to the local lord
whose land they farmed.
Under the system of feudalism that
dominated in Western Europe beginning in about the 11th century, kings, nobles,
and church rulers all collected taxes. Kings derived income from their lands,
from import and export duties, and from the various feudal dues and services
owed by their vassals. For the most part, church officials and nobles were
granted exemption from royal taxes, so the burden of taxation fell heavily on
the peasantry. When King John of England tried to increase his income by a
series of heavy scutages (payments that knights made in lieu of military
service), the feudal nobility refused to pay. In 1215 they forced the king to
sign the Magna Carta, a document in which he agreed to collect scutage only with
the “common consent” of his barons—thus limiting the king’s power to tax.
The Roman Catholic church was a major tax
collector during the Middle Ages. One of the most important sources of church
revenue was the tithe, a compulsory payment of one-tenth of a person’s
harvest and livestock. The church also collected various fees, fines, and tolls,
and required clergy members, such as bishops and archbishops, to make payments
to the papacy in Rome.
An important development toward the end of
the feudal period was the dramatic growth in the number and population of towns
and cities. These urban centers collected revenues using taxes on property as
well as sales taxes on certain items.
C | 16th Century to Modern Period |
Over a period of time, feudalism faded and
strong centralized states emerged in Europe. During the 16th and 17th centuries,
these states relied heavily on revenues generated by the king’s own estates and
by taxes on land. In England, the power of Parliament grew steadily because the
kings and queens had to convene it frequently to obtain money. In 1689 the
English Bill of Rights guaranteed that the king could not tax without
Parliament’s consent.
By the 18th century, England started
imposing various taxes on transactions. Taxes on imported goods (tariffs)
assumed great importance, as did taxes on a wide variety of commodities,
including sugar, meat, chocolate, alcohol, coffee, candles, and soap. As time
passed, people became dissatisfied with this system of public finance for
several reasons. First, although the English government levied some taxes on
commodities consumed only by the rich—window glass, for example, which was a
great luxury at the time—in general people perceived that the burden of taxes
fell mostly on the poor. In addition, tax systems did not generate as much
revenue as the governing classes wanted. Finally, economists and political
leaders began realizing that by reducing trade, tariffs created economic losses
for society.
In the late 19th and early 20th centuries,
concerns about both fairness and the ability of tax systems to generate
sufficient revenue led governments to enact income taxes. In 1799 Britain
enacted the first national income tax, to finance the Napoleonic Wars. The
government discontinued the tax when the war ended in 1815, but revived it in
1842. The first progressive income tax—which imposed a greater tax burden on
people with higher incomes—was introduced in Prussia in 1853. Other countries
introduced progressive income taxation in subsequent decades, including Britain
in 1907, the United States in 1913, and France in 1917. Although income taxes
generated little revenue at first, today they play a major role in all modern
tax systems.
D | Taxation in the United States |
D1 | Early Colonies |
During the 17th and early 18th
centuries, local and provincial governments in the British colonies of North
America levied taxes to finance schools, road building, military expenditures,
law enforcement, and in some cases, churches. Cities and counties levied
property taxes based on a person’s ownership of land and livestock and imposed
poll taxes on adult men—who also paid the poll taxes of their slaves, servants,
and hired workers. Some communities imposed an additional tax on doctors,
lawyers, and other professionals and artisans whose special training gave them
greater earning power. The colonies taxed imported goods from Europe and the
West Indies (but not from Britain), and some colonies taxed certain exports,
such as tobacco or furs. Many colonies collected excise taxes on liquor from
tavern owners.
Taxation of the American colonies by
Great Britain was one of the major causes of the American Revolution. Before the
French and Indian War (1754-1763), Britain imposed few taxes on the colonies.
The war left Britain deeply in debt, however, and the British Parliament
insisted that the prosperous colonies help pay for the cost of protecting them.
In 1764 Parliament passed the Sugar Act, which taxed non-British imports of
sugar and molasses and, unlike the Molasses Act of 1733, was strictly enforced
(see Sugar and Molasses Acts). A year later Parliament passed the Stamp
Act, which required colonists to buy and place tax stamps on all legal
documents, licenses, newspapers, pamphlets, and playing cards. Both taxes caused
widespread resentment among the colonists. They believed that the British
government had no right to tax the colonies without allowing them representation
in Parliament—the principle of “no taxation without representation.” In
response, colonists rioted and boycotted British goods, causing the British
Parliament to repeal the Stamp Act in 1766.
In 1767 Parliament passed the Townshend
Acts, which imposed duties on a variety of imports to the colonies. Colonists
responded with violent protests—one riot led to the Boston Massacre—and by again
boycotting British goods. In 1770 Britain repealed all but the tea duty, leaving
it as a symbol of its right to tax the colonies. The Tea Act, passed by
Parliament in 1773, lifted tea import duties in England but retained them in the
colonies. The measure incensed American patriots and resulted in the Boston Tea
Party, in which patriots dumped shiploads of British tea into Boston Harbor .
War broke out between the colonies and Britain in 1775. See American
Revolution.
D2 | A New Nation |
The Articles of Confederation, adopted
in 1781 as the first constitution of the United States, denied the federal
government the power of taxation. The federal government relied on donations
from individual states for its revenues, but sometimes states refused to make
payments to the federal government. The inability of Congress to tax rendered it
largely ineffectual. For example, Congress was unable to meet patriot officers’
demands for back pay, and it could not pay interest on the war debt.
The federal government obtained the
power to levy taxes with the ratification of the Constitution of the United
States in 1789. The Revenue Act of 1791 established tariffs on select imported
goods and imposed excise taxes on a variety of goods, including horse-drawn
carriages, distilled liquor, snuff, and refined sugar. These taxes proved
extremely unpopular. Discontent boiled over into the Whiskey Rebellion of 1794,
in which farmers protested a tax on whiskey of 30 cents per gallon. The
government repealed most of these sales taxes in 1801 but temporarily reinstated
them to finance the War of 1812. During the Civil War (1861-1865) the Union
government financed itself through an elaborate system of excise taxes,
including taxes on alcohol, tobacco, manufactured goods, legal documents, and
bowling alleys. Until the beginning of the 20th century, various excise taxes,
along with tariffs, were the largest sources of revenue for the federal
government.
D3 | Introduction of Income Taxes |
The federal government first imposed an
individual income tax in 1862 as an emergency means of financing the Civil War.
It also established the Bureau of Internal Revenue, predecessor of the Internal
Revenue Service. Tax rates were 3 percent on income from $600 to $10,000 and 5
percent on income above $10,000. Later in the war the maximum rate increased to
10 percent of income. In 1872 the government eliminated the tax because the
extraordinary revenue needs of the war no longer existed.
As the 19th century came to a close,
sentiment in favor of income taxation grew. Just as in other countries, the
public believed that sales taxes and tariffs permitted wealthy people to avoid
their fair share of the burden of financing government. Congress passed a
progressive income tax in 1894, but the Supreme Court declared it
unconstitutional a year later. The Court ruled that the Constitution required
taxes on people to be collected in proportion to a state’s population, and that
income taxes violated this requirement. In 1909 the government imposed a tax on
the income of corporations for the first time. At the same time, proponents of
an individual income tax pressed for a constitutional amendment. The 16th
Amendment, ratified in 1913, authorized individual income taxation. It gave
Congress the power “to lay and collect taxes on incomes, from whatever source
derived, without apportionment among the several States, and without regard to
any census or enumeration.”
In late 1913 Congress enacted a tax on
annual income over $3,000, with marginal (bracket) rates ranging from 1 to 7
percent. At the time, few people earned more than $3,000 per year, so less than
1 percent of the population even filed tax returns. The costs of World War I
(1914-1918) led Congress to raise income taxes and make more people eligible to
pay them. In 1935 the government imposed a tax on payrolls to finance the Social
Security system. In 1943 it began mandatory withholding of individual income
taxes from payrolls, which dramatically increased the ease of administering the
income tax. By 1945 marginal rates ranged from 23 percent to 94 percent. The
maximum marginal tax rate dropped to 70 percent in 1965.
In the 1980s President Ronald Reagan
made tax reform a centerpiece of his presidency. He embraced a policy of
supply-side economics, which predicted that lower taxes would stimulate
work effort and saving. The Economic Recovery and Tax Act of 1981 reduced
business taxes and lowered the maximum marginal tax rate to 50 percent. The
landmark Tax Reform Act of 1986 further lowered this rate to 28 percent. It also
ended deductions for interest paid on consumer loans and student debt, raised
the capital gains tax rate to that of ordinary income, and eliminated some
special provisions and loopholes in tax laws.
In 1990 President George H. W. Bush and
Congress agreed to raise taxes to trim the budget deficit, which had grown
substantially in the 1980s. Their tax bill raised the highest marginal tax rate
to 31 percent. President Bill Clinton's deficit-reduction bill, passed by
Congress in 1993, sharply increased corporation taxes, increased tax credits for
the poor, and raised taxes on upper-income individuals. The maximum marginal tax
rate on individual income increased to 39.6 percent. In the 1990s Congress also
restored preferential tax rates for income from capital gains.
President George W. Bush, like Reagan,
also made tax cuts the centerpiece of his administration. Bush’s Economic Growth
and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 gradually lowered tax brackets, with
the top tax bracket dropping to 35 percent by 2006. The law also gradually
increased exemptions for the estate tax and eliminated the estate tax entirely
in 2010. A second round of tax cuts in 2003 immediately lowered the top tax
bracket to 35 percent, reduced the tax on capital gains for most investors from
20 percent to 15 percent, lowered the tax on dividends from a maximum rate of
38.6 percent to 15 percent, and increased the child tax credit for families in
certain income brackets.
The 2003 tax cuts were particularly
controversial and narrowly passed Congress. Critics, mostly Democrats, charged
that the cuts would worsen the nation’s budget deficit, making it more likely
that popular social programs such as Social Security and Medicare would have to
be curtailed in the future. Some critics even charged that this was the intent
of the tax cuts. The tax cuts were also criticized for favoring the wealthy and
shifting the tax burden to middle-class taxpayers, creating a more regressive
tax system in the United States. Some wealthy Americans, such as investor Warren
Buffett, opposed the reduction of the tax on dividends and the elimination of
the estate tax because they gave disproportionate tax benefits to the rich. The
Bush administration, however, argued that the cuts were necessary to stimulate
the economy and create jobs. As with previous tax legislation, sunset provisions
were incorporated into the new tax law. The new tax rates on dividends and
capital gains were scheduled to expire in 2004.
E | Taxation in Canada |
The first known taxes in Canada were
export taxes on furs imposed by the French regime in 1650. The French government
soon replaced these with tariffs on imported goods. Tariffs continued to be of
major importance during the period of British rule, which began in 1763. The
British North America Act of 1867 stated that the provinces could levy income
taxes, but could no longer levy tariffs. However, the levying of income taxes on
individuals and businesses did not become widespread in the provinces until the
end of the 19th century.
In 1917 the federal government, which had
relied primarily on excise taxes, created both a personal income tax and a
corporate income tax, both of which had previously been levied only by
provinces. The federal government introduced a general sales tax in 1920. All
the provinces created gasoline taxes in the 1920s and collected taxes on alcohol
sales. During World War II the provinces suspended their income taxes.
After World War II, the federal government
took over the income tax from the provinces, paying them a fee for this right.
In 1962 the provinces regained the right to levy income taxes. All provinces
soon imposed individual income taxes. (Except in the province of Québec,
provincial income taxes are collected by the federal government and then given
over to provincial governments.) Also, from 1973 to 1990, all provinces adopted
some form of corporate income tax.
In 1991 the federal government introduced
a goods and services tax (GST). This broad-based tax applies to most goods and
services, although certain commodities, such as basic groceries and medical
supplies, are exempt from the tax. In 2000 Canada adopted one of the largest tax
cuts in its history. It was designed to reduce personal taxes an average of 15
percent over a five-year period.
See also Public Finance.
No comments:
Post a Comment