I | INTRODUCTION |
Macroeconomics, branch of economics concerned with the
aggregate, or overall, economy. Macroeconomics deals with economic
factors such as total national output and income, unemployment, balance of
payments, and the rate of inflation. It is distinct from microeconomics, which
is the study of the composition of output such as the supply and demand for
individual goods and services, the way they are traded in markets, and the
pattern of their relative prices.
At the basis of macroeconomics is an
understanding of what constitutes national output, or national income, and the
related concept of gross national product (GNP). The GNP is the total value of
goods and services produced in an economy during a given period of time, usually
a year. The measure of what a country's economic activity produces in the end is
called final demand. The main determinants of final demand are
consumption (personal expenditure on items such as food, clothing, appliances,
and cars), investment (spending by businesses on items such as new facilities
and equipment), government spending, and net exports (exports minus
imports).
Macroeconomic theory is largely concerned with
what determines the size of GNP, its stability, and its relationship to
variables such as unemployment and inflation. The size of a country's potential
GNP at any moment in time depends on its factors of production—labor and
capital—and its technology. Over time the country's labor force, capital stock,
and technology will change, and the determination of long-run changes in a
country's productive potential is the subject matter of one branch of
macroeconomic theory known as growth theory.
The study of macroeconomics is relatively new,
generally beginning with the ideas of British economist John Maynard Keynes in
the 1930s. Keynes's ideas revolutionized thinking in several areas of
macroeconomics, including unemployment, money supply, and inflation.
II | KEYNESIAN THEORY AND UNEMPLOYMENT |
Unemployment causes a great deal of social
distress and concern; as a result, the causes and consequences of unemployment
have received the most attention in macroeconomic theory. Until the publication
in 1936 of The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money by
Keynes, large-scale unemployment was generally explained in terms of rigidity in
the labor market that prevented wages from falling to a level at which the labor
market would be in equilibrium. Equilibrium would be reached when pressure from
members of the labor force seeking work had bid down the wage to the point where
either some dropped out of the labor market (the supply of labor fell) or firms
became willing to take on more labor given that the lower wage increased the
profitability of hiring more workers (demand increased). If, however, some
rigidity prevented wages from falling to the point where supply and demand for
labor were at equilibrium, then unemployment could persist. Such an obstacle
could be, for example, trade union action to maintain minimum wages or
minimum-wage legislation.
Keynes's major innovation was to argue that
persistent unemployment might be caused by a deficiency in demand for production
or services, rather than by a disequilibrium in the labor market. Such a
deficiency of demand could be explained by a failure of planned (intended)
investment to match planned (intended) savings. Savings constitute a leakage in
the circular flow by which the incomes earned in the course of producing goods
or services are transferred back into demand for other goods and services. A
leakage in the circular flow of incomes would tend to reduce the level of total
demand. “Real” investment, known as capital formation (the production of
machines, factories, housing, and so on), has the opposite effect—it is an
injection into the circular flow relating income to output—and tends to raise
the level of demand.
In the earlier classical models of
unemployment, such as the one described above, deficiency of demand in the
aggregate market for goods and services (known by the short-hand term as the
goods market) was ruled out. It was believed that any discrepancy between
planned savings and planned investment would be eliminated by changes in the
rate of interest. Thus, for example, if planned savings exceeded planned
investment, the rate of interest would fall, which would reduce the supply of
savings and, at the same time, increase the desire of companies to borrow money
to invest in machines, buildings, and so on. In other words, changes in the rate
of interest would provide the equilibrating force bringing the overall
(aggregate) goods market into equilibrium in the same way that changes in, say,
the price of apples would be the equilibrating force bringing the supply and
demand for apples into equilibrium.
In the Keynesian model, changes in the level
of output and income bring planned savings and investment into equilibrium, and
thereby lead to equilibrium in total national income and output. However, this
equilibrium level of income and output is not necessarily the level of output at
which the demand for labor equals the supply of labor. Furthermore, Keynes
maintained, a cut in wages in such a situation would not help eliminate
unemployment. Keynes was not the first economist to explain unemployment in
terms of an aggregate deficiency of demand in the goods market. The 19th-century
British economist Thomas Robert Malthus and others had advanced similar
explanations.
The Keynesian revolution implied that, in the
terminology of macroeconomics, the goods market could be at an underemployment
equilibrium, in that it did not ensure equilibrium in the labor market. In such
a labor market, employers would not employ workers up to the point where it
would have been profitable for them to do so had there been adequate demand for
their output. Concepts of underemployment equilibrium, and related concepts of
constrained demand for labor were extensively developed in subsequent
years.
Keynes's emphasis on demand as the key
determinant of output in the short run stimulated developments in many other
fields of macroeconomics. It was partly instrumental in the development of
national income accounting, which measures the components of GNP—consumption,
investment, government spending and net exports. The Keynesian approach also
stimulated analysis of the factors influencing these components of GNP. For
example, economists have analyzed how aggregate consumer demand is related to
income levels and how likely it is to change when rates of interest change.
III | MONEY SUPPLY |
Theories regarding the money supply are
central to macroeconomics. They are also the subject of debate between
Keynesians and monetarists (economists who believe that growth in the money
supply is the most important factor that determines economic growth). The
classical or pre-Keynes view was that the interest rate led to a balance between
savings and investment, which in turn would cause equilibrium in the goods
market. Keynes disagreed and believed that the interest rate was largely a
monetary phenomenon; its chief function was to balance the unpredictable supply
and demand for money, not savings and investment. This view explained why the
amount of savings was not always correlated with the amount of investment or the
interest rate.
Keynesians and monetarists also disagree
about how changes in the money supply affect employment and output. Some
economists argue that an increase in the supply of money will tend to reduce
interest rates, which in turn will stimulate investment and total demand.
Therefore, an alternative way of reducing unemployment would be to expand the
money supply. Keynesians and monetarists disagree on how successful this method
of raising output would be. Keynesians believe that under conditions of
underemployment, the increased spending will lead to greater output and
employment. Monetarists, however, generally believe that an increase in the
money supply will lead to inflation in the long run.
IV | INFLATION |
For several decades after World War II
(1939-1945) the main inflation theories were demand-pull and cost-push. The
cost-push theory basically emphasized the role of excessive increases in wages
relative to productivity increases as a cause of inflation, whereas the
demand-pull theory tended to attribute inflation more to excess demand in the
goods market caused by expansion of the money supply. A central concept in
inflationary theory since the mid-1950s has been the Phillips curve,
which relates the level of unemployment to the rate of inflation. The Phillips
curve suggests that society can make a choice between various combinations of
inflation rate and unemployment level. Many economists, however, dispute whether
such a choice really exists, saying that in order to keep unemployment under
control it will be necessary to accept continuously increasing inflation. At the
same time many other economists dispute whether a stable relationship between
unemployment and the level of real wage demands exists.
V | MODERN THEORIES |
During the last few decades there have been
numerous refinements of the Keynesian theory of unemployment. For example,
although there is still much disagreement as to the importance of wage rigidity,
significant progress has been made in explaining it without recourse to trade
union behavior or government regulation. At first it seemed difficult to
reconcile the notion of wage rigidity with the usual economist's assumption that
people seek to maximize utility or satisfaction and would be willing to accept a
lower wage in order to get a job. However, by widening the range of variables
over which individuals optimize to include variables such as loyalty and
self-respect, it has become easier to reconcile labor market disequilibrium with
the usual assumptions of optimizing behavior.
Macroeconomic theories regarding the way that
the determinants of total final demand operate form the basis of large
macroeconomic models of the economy that are used in economic forecasting to
make predictions of output and employment and related variables. During the last
few years, the record of most such predictions has been poor, and an analysis of
the errors has led to continual revisions of the basic models and refinements of
the theory.
No comments:
Post a Comment